International encyclopedia of the social - William A. Darity(6).pdf

(6155 KB) Pobierz
160132830 UNPDF
International Encyclopedia of the
Social Sciences, 2nd edition
International Encyclopedia of the
Social Sciences, 2nd edition
VOLUME 2
COHABITATION–ETHICS IN EXPERIMENTATION
William A. Darity Jr.
EDITOR IN CHIEF
160132830.001.png 160132830.002.png 160132830.003.png
C
COGNITIVE
DISTORTIONS
SEE Psychotherapy.
problematic for female cohabitants. This compares to
500,000 cohabiting couples in 1970.
This growing popularity of cohabitation has resulted
in a concern among some observers that the practice pre-
sents a challenge to marriage as a method of coupling.
They argue that marriage is being redefined as one of sev-
eral choices. The literature suggests that for older cohabi-
tants and for African American couples this lifestyle
choice does represent an alternative to marriage. For most
Americans, however, marriage remains the primary choice
for coupling. Cohabitation is increasingly viewed as a
transitional stage between single life and marriage, rather
than as an alternative to marriage. Unlike in the United
States, however, cohabitation is a significant alternative to
marriage for young Scandinavian couples. In addition,
increasing economic inequality in the United States is
decreasing the opportunities for marriage among less-
affluent Americans.
The most commonly cited reasons for moving in
together are romance, convenience, the need for housing,
and the chance to save money. How well do cohabitants
get along with each other? Recent research has found that
cohabiting couples are significantly less satisfied in their
unions than those who are legally married. This is due, in
part, to the fact that cohabiting couples often have more
precarious economic circumstances than do married cou-
ples. In addition, the presence of children, which reduces
satisfaction levels for both married and cohabiting cou-
ples, has a more profound effect on nonmarital unions.
This is significant in that children are present for 40 per-
cent of cohabiting couples. Further, it is widely assumed
that the outcomes are worse for children raised by cohab-
COGNITIVE MATRIX
SEE Rituals.
COHABITATION
Cohabitation is defined as a situation in which opposite-
sex couples live together outside of marriage. Much of the
literature on cohabitation is derived from research find-
ings by sociologists and psychologists, which places this
literature in a central position within the social sciences.
This entry provides a brief discussion of who cohabits,
why people choose to cohabit, and the consequences of
cohabitation for couples, children, and society.
Cohabitation has become increasingly popular since
the 1960s, with the majority of young adults in the
United States experiencing cohabitation. For most cou-
ples, this is a relatively short-term experience, with only
one-third of American couples cohabiting for at least two
years and only 10 percent doing so for at least five years.
About 60 percent of these unions eventually result in mar-
riage. In 2007 nearly five million opposite-sex couples in
the United States were living together outside of marriage,
largely without legal protections, which is particularly
INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES, 2ND EDITION
1
 
Cohort Effects
iting couples, as opposed to children raised by married
parents.
Lastly, does living with one’s partner prior to marriage
increase the likelihood of success after marriage? Couples
who move in together before marriage have up to two
times the odds of divorce compared to those couples who
do not live together prior to marriage (Blackwell and
Lichter 2000). Some argue that living together creates
social pressure to get married, which can contribute to
poor mate selection.
SEE ALSO Family; Marriage
to be integrated of order one [denoted I(1)]. Growth rates
of these series do not tend to drift, which is consistent
with the growth rates being nonintegrated, I.E., inte-
grated of order zero [denoted I(0)]. Moreover, efficient-
market theories in economics and finance suggest that
asset and commodity prices follow a random walk, which
is the simplest I(1) process.
Cointegration occurs when a relationship ties
together nonstationary economic time series such that a
combination of those time series is I(0). The concepts of
integration and cointegration are intrinsically statistical in
nature. Cointegration formalizes, in statistical terms, the
property of a long-run relation between integrated eco-
nomic variables.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Blackwell, Debra L., and Daniel T. Lichter. 2000. Mate
Selection among Married and Cohabiting Couples. Journal of
Family Issues 21 (3): 275–302.
Willetts, Marion C. 2006. Union Quality Comparisons Between
Long-Term Heterosexual Cohabitation and Legal Marriage.
Journal of Family Issues 27 (1): 110–127.
SOME ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS
OF COINTEGRATION
While cointegration is a statistical concept, it has eco-
nomic implications. For example, it plays important roles
in five aspects of economics: (1) long-run relations, (2)
agent optimization, (3) the problem of nonsense regres-
sions, (4) equilibrium correction (or error correction)
models (ECMs), and (5) economic forecasting.
First, cointegration embeds the economic notion of a
long-run relationship between economic variables in a sta-
tistical model of those variables. If a long-run relation
exists, then the variables are cointegrated.
Second, market forces or optimizing behavior often
provide an economic rationale for cointegration. For
instance, consumers’ expenditure and income may be
cointegrated because of economic agents’ budget con-
straints or because of intertemporal optimization plans for
lifetime saving.
Third, the statistical theory of unit-root processes
aids inference about the empirical existence of cointegra-
tion. Econometric theory historically relied on the
assumption of stationary data even though many observed
economic time series were trending and nonstationary.
Cointegration explicitly allows for nonstationarity, thus
providing a sounder basis for empirical inference.
Cointegration also clarifies the problem of nonsense
regressions, in which intrinsically unrelated nonstationary
time series are highly correlated with each other.
Fourth, cointegration implies, and is implied by, the
existence of an equilibrium correction representation of
the relevant variables. Cointegration thus solidifies the
statistical and economic bases for the empirically success-
ful class of equilibrium correction models, in which past
disequilibria in levels have an effect on current changes in
the variables. Through ECMs, cointegration provides a
systematic framework for jointly analyzing short-run (e.g.,
cyclical) and long-run properties. This framework also
resolves the debate on whether to model data in levels or
Paul R. Newcomb
COHORT EFFECTS
SEE Period Effects.
COINCIDENT
INDICATORS
SEE Lagging, Leading, and Coincident Indicators.
COINTEGRATION
Time-series data consist of multiple observations of firms,
households, persons, or other entities over several time
periods. Many economic time series have empirical distri-
butions that are nonconstant over time, with changing
means and variances, making these series nonstationary.
Stochastic trends occur when there are persistent long-
term movements in time series data; and such trends rep-
resent a major source of nonstationarity, causing variables
to drift over time. Series with stochastic trends are thus
called “integrated” or “unit-root” processes.
In 1982, Charles Nelson and Charles Plosser showed
that, empirically, many macroeconomic time series appear
2
INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES, 2ND EDITION
Cointegration
in differences, with classical econometric models and
George Box and Gwilym Jenkins’s time-series models
both being special cases of ECMs.
Fifth, optimal forecasts of cointegrated variables are
themselves cointegrated. Hence, the existence of cointe-
gration may improve the long-term forecasting of eco-
nomic time series.
unbalanced regressions involving variables of different
orders of integration.
Economic theory rarely specifies orders of integration
for variables, so a practitioner must analyze the data for
both integration and cointegration. While the presence of
unit roots complicates inference because some associated
limiting distributions are nonstandard, critical values have
been tabulated for many common cases. David Dickey
and Wayne Fuller calculated critical values of tests for unit
roots in univariate processes, and many robust unit-root
tests have subsequently been developed.
Numerous cointegration tests have also been
designed. In 1987, Engle and Granger proposed a single-
equation approach that is intuitive and easy to implement,
though it includes nuisance parameters in inference and
may lack power (see Hendry 1986). A test of cointegra-
tion is also feasible in the corresponding ECM (see Neil
Ericsson and James MacKinnon 2002).
Søren Johansen has provided a system-based approach
in which cointegration relations are estimated via maxi-
mum likelihood in a vector autoregression (VAR).
Johansen’s test statistics for cointegration generalize the
Dickey-Fuller statistic to the multivariate context. Several
authors have tabulated critical values, which are also
embodied in software such as Cats for Rats and PcGive. In
Johansen’s framework, hypotheses about cointegration
properties are also testable. For instance, testing the long-
run homogeneity of money with respect to prices is equiv-
alent to testing whether the logs of money and prices are
cointegrated with a unit coefficient. Other hypotheses,
such as weak exogeneity, can be tested in Johansen’s frame-
work as well. Weak exogeneity is satisfied if the cointegrat-
ing vector entering the conditional model does not appear
in the marginal model of the conditioning variables. Under
weak exogeneity, inference on those parameters from the
conditional model alone is without loss of information rel-
ative to inference in the complete system.
In summary, cointegration and equilibrium correc-
tion help us understand short-run and long-run proper-
ties of economic data, and they provide a framework for
testing economic hypotheses about growth and fluctua-
tions. At the outset of an empirical investigation, eco-
nomic time series should be analyzed for integration and
cointegration, and tests are readily available to do so. Such
analyses can aid in the interpretation of subsequent results
and may suggest possible modeling strategies and specifi-
cations that are consistent with the data, while also reduc-
ing the risk of spurious regressions.
HISTORY
The history of cointegration was examined by David
Hendry in “The Nobel Memorial Prize for Clive W. J.
Granger” (2004). Hendry and Mary Morgan, in The
Foundations of Econometric Analysis (1995), highlight the
following events in that history. In 1901, R. H. Hooker
illustrated and analyzed the difficulties attendant to non-
stationarity, which he viewed as “common trends.” In
1926, G. Udny Yule showed that I(1) and I(2) observa-
tions would generate “nonsense correlations”; for exam-
ple, high correlations lacking causal explanation, such as
between church marriages and mortality rates. In 1974,
Clive Granger and Paul Newbold reemphasized the dan-
gers of nonsense correlations, and Peter Phillips presented
a formal analysis in 1986, which he updated in 1998.
Klein’s great ratios of economics (e.g., of consumption to
income) suggested that variables’ levels can be closely
related. J. Denis Sargan established the link between
static-equilibrium economic theory and ECMs in 1964.
In the 1980s, Granger and Robert Engle developed coin-
tegration analysis as such.
MODEL SPECIFICATION
In 1987, Engle and Granger established an isomorphism
between cointegration and ECMs. Cointegration entails,
and is entailed by, an ECM, which explicitly embeds a
steady-state solution for its variables, while also allowing
them to deviate from that steady state in the short run.
In a nonstochastic steady state, an equilibrium relation
would typically be motivated by economic theory. Hence,
economic hypotheses are testable in a cointegration
framework. In empirical work, conditional ECMs have
been popular and may be interpretable as agents’ contin-
gent plans. Applications include wages and prices, con-
sumers’ expenditure, and money demand.
TESTING FOR INTEGRATION AND
COINTEGRATION
Cointegration makes the economic concept of equilib-
rium operational; that is, data allow tests of whether a
long-run relation holds. With suitable tests, asymptoti-
cally correct inferences can be obtained. In addition, spu-
rious regressions can be detected and avoided, as can
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Banerjee, Anindya, Juan J. Dolado, John W. Galbraith, and
David F. Hendry. 1993. Co-integration, Error Correction, and
INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES, 2ND EDITION
3
Zgłoś jeśli naruszono regulamin